A version of this blog was later published in “Social Protection in Developing Countries: Reforming Systems”, eds Bender, Kaltenborn and Pfleiderer, Routledge, Oxford, UK (2013)
Social protection has come a long way in the decade since it
first entered the development discourse. There is now generally a recognition
that the old development paradigm ("the poor are the problem") is
bankrupt. This paradigm focussed development on promoting economic growth, waited
for economic growth to reduce poverty, provided residual interim safety nets to
those who could not benefit immediately, and left donors to step in with
expensive "emergency" assistance when necessary. This has not worked.
The emerging development paradigm ("the poor are the
solution") is predicated on the provision of comprehensive social
protection which will allow the poor themselves to participate in the
generation of economic growth; this in turn will reduce poverty and the cost of
providing social protection, and will also reduce the need for emergency
assistance, thus freeing donor resources to help fund further development.
Over the last decade, donors and their international
development partners have indeed done a lot to promote and support these
significant advances. But they could have done better. There is a serious, and
continuing, problem that donors and IDPs fall into four competing camps, which
this paper characterises as the "Four Horsemen of the Donor Apocalypse":
the Productivists, the Ten-Percenters, the Instrumentalists and the
Universalists.
The
White Horse
I watched as the Lamb
opened the first of the seven seals. Then I heard one of the four living
creatures say in a voice like thunder, "Come and see!" I looked, and
there before me was a white horse! Its rider held a bow, and he was given a
crown, and he rode out as a conqueror bent on conquest.
The Productivists are led by the World Bank and the IMF. The
characteristics of their vision of social protection are that it must be
targeted at the poorest; that the poorest should preferably be identified
through "proxy means testing"; and that no-one should be given
"something for nothing". This means that they favour public works
programmes, social action funds and conditional cash transfers (for all of
which it is of course much easier to persuade Governments to take substantial
loans, since such programmes are also demonstrably producing physical, social
and human assets). Examples of Productivist programmes abound, for example in
Latin America, in the Philippines, and in Ethiopia, Rwanda and Tanzania.
There are some concerns with this "poor relief" approach,
however. The first is that the incremental benefits of conditionality, pushed
hard by the Bank, are unproven (or at best controversial) . The second is that
proxy means testing is, by the Bank's own admission, "most appropriately
used where a country has reasonably high administrative capacity", and it has
been shown elsewhere to be highly inaccurate (watch this Wahenga space). And the
third is that, while the Bank has (belatedly) adopted the "3 Ps"
framework for social protection, it has bizarrely dropped the concept of
"provision". Its "3 Ps" are promotion, prevention and
protection, with the latter introducing a worrying semantic circularity. But
the more fundamental problem is that, the way it is defined,
"protection" (ie protection " from destitution and catastrophic
losses of human capital ") is little different from "prevention"
(ie protection "against drops in well-being from income and expenditure
shocks") - in that both presuppose that people have something to start
with, which needs to be "protected" or its disposal
"prevented". And what we have lost from the original "3Ps"
is any concept of "provision" - the idea that there are groups of
people (who many would argue should be the core target groups for social
protection) who have virtually nothing to "protect" or
"prevent", and who rely on social protection just to survive. This
might include the elderly, the disabled, street-children, marginalised groups.
The worry is that by excluding this "provision" function, the Bank is
inching SP away from the poorest and most vulnerable, and towards those with
economic growth potential ... and therefore better prospects for their
"lending operations".
The
Red Horse
When the Lamb opened
the second seal, I heard the second living creature say, "Come and
see!" Then another horse came out, a fiery red one.
The Ten-Percenters are led by UNICEF (though - in fairness -
not all of UNICEF). The principal characteristic of their vision of social
protection is that it should use community-based targeting to identify the most
labour-constrained households among the "ultra-poor", which -
somewhat mysteriously - appears to equate ubiquitously to ten percent of the
total population. The identified beneficiaries are then given unconditional
cash transfers, sometimes with additional incentives if they have school-going
children. This approach began with the tiny, but much-feted, Kalomo pilot in
Zambia, and it has since been rolled out, with little modification to adapt to
differing national circumstances, in Malawi and Liberia. More recently,
Zimbabwe and Uganda have escaped with variants on the original.
Here the concern, rather than being with the "3
Ps", is that it has "no Ps": no practical basis, no political
support, and no potential! On the contrary, there are multiple problems, many
of which have been discussed in earlier RHVP Comments and Briefs. First, it is
almost impossible to identify the poorest and most-labour constrained ten
percent, especially in countries where over seventy percent of the population
are churning in and out of poverty. It is difficult enough even on a pilot
scale with extensive external resources and additional "project"
funding: it is totally impractical on a national scale. This can lead to
problems of moral hazard and even social conflict. Second, even if it were
possible, the income from the transfer to the poorest households will result in
them rapidly "leap-frogging" up the wealth distribution, so that they
will very soon no longer be the poorest. This can lead to problems of equity
and the need to retarget frequently. Third, the arbitrary choice of ten percent
- essentially a budget rationing tool - cannot be applied universally with any
semblance of fairness: there are huge variations in the extent of poverty
between, and even within, different districts and communities. As a result,
none of the cited examples has been successfully scaled up: and in Zambia,
showcase of the Ten-Percenters, the Government has recently expressed its clear
preference for a categorical child benefit over the ten percent model that has
been pushed so hard and for so long.
The
Black Horse
When the Lamb opened
the third seal, I heard the third living creature say, "Come and
see!" I looked, and there before me was a black horse! Its rider was
holding a pair of scales in his hand.
The Instrumentalists are led by ILO, which has rallied an
impressive array of UN and other agencies behind its Social Protection Floor(SPF)
initiative. Emerging from an employment and "decent work" perspective,
the SPF comprises four main components: access to health services; child or family
support; income support for the unemployed; and income security for elderly and
disabled persons. If you believe the propaganda, examples of the successful
implementation of the SPF are everywhere, even in countries where social
protection has been evolving at its own pace and in its own way for many years
before the term SPF was even coined: these include Mexico, Brazil, Argentina,
South Africa, Bolivia, Sri Lanka, Ghana, Haiti, East Timor, etc, etc, etc.
The primary concern with the SPF is to know "which P?":
is it a process or is it a prescription? The correct answer is that it is a
process. But - for one reason or another - it has been mis-sold, and now
suffers from an image problem. Many stakeholders, including some countries and
some key donors, perceive it as being too prescriptive, with a mandate to roll
out a social protection carpet of standard instruments: health insurance/fee
waivers, child grants, unemployment benefits and old-age/disability pensions.
To some extent, this misperception in understandable: the ILO has itself recently
made a number of presentations describing the SPF as "four essential
social transfers" and "four essential social security
guarantees", in both cases specifically citing the instruments of
"family/child benefits", "social assistance", and
"pensions". The ILO public relations machine will have to work hard to
retrieve the situation and demonstrate convincingly that the SPF is what it
says it is: a recognition that "each country has different social needs,
development objectives and fiscal capacity to achieve them, and will choose a
different set of policies"; and that the role of the SPF "through a
coordinated country response [is to] facilitate and accelerate the introduction
or strengthening of sustainable context-specific social protection systems".
The
Pale Horse
When the Lamb opened
the fourth seal, I heard the voice of the fourth living creature say,
"Come and see!" I looked and there before me was a pale horse!
The Universalists are a diverse (and fluid) crowd: they
include a number of the big international NGOs, a handful of bilateral donors
including the Nordics and DFID ... and - let us be honest - RHVP. The
characteristics of their vision of social protection are that it should be rights-based,
that it should use predominantly universal approaches and categorical
targeting, that it should favour demand-led employment guarantee schemes over
supply-led discretionary public works projects, and that it should deliver
unconditional cash transfers with no strings attached. Examples can be found in
many OECD countries, but also in South Africa, Botswana and Nambia, and (at
least partially or incipiently) in lower income countries such as Lesotho,
Nepal, Uganda and Zambia.
The primary concern here is again with "3 Ps": how
do we pay, pay, pay? There is no doubt that such universal schemes will cost
more to implement, and this is often raised as an impossible hurdle. Yet
experience has shown that when such schemes are introduced, they are more
sustainable: more people benefit from them, understand them, and accept them as
fair; so more people vote for them; so they become more popular politically; so
they attract a greater share of the national budget. And so, ultimately, it can
be argued that the poorest get more benefit from universal schemes than from
programmes targeted more narrowly at them. One option to defray the costs is to
introduce such schemes progressively: in other words, to set eligibility for a
social pension at a relatively high age such as 70 and reduce it gradually, or
to start a child benefit at a young age such as 2 and then increase it over
time (like South Africa has done), as the evidence of beneficial impacts
generates increased public and political support. Experience shows that
governments will devote much more substantial shares of their budgets to
universal programmes than to poverty-targeted ones. For example, the universal
social pensions in Mauritius, Lesotho and Nepal command more than double the
resources as a share of GDP than the means-tested pensions in Cape Verde,
Argentina and India; and it is often overlooked that the budget of the vaunted
poverty-targeted Bolsa Familia in
Brazil is dwarfed by that of the country's near-universal rural and urban
pension programmes.
Angels and Demons
They were given power over a fourth of the earth to kill
by sword, famine and plague, and by the wild beasts of the earth.
The funny thing about the Four Horsemen of the Apocalypse is
that no-one really knows what they mean. The popular, more dramatic view is
that they symbolise tribulation, and are the harbingers, respectively, of
conquest, war, famine and death. But there is another school of thought that
equates them with the angels of the four winds (Michael, Gabriel,
Raphael
and Uriel),
who are often associated with the four cardinal directions. And this seems more
appropriate in terms of our Four donor Horsemen: the danger is that, whatever
the strengths and weaknesses of their competing visions, they are pulling in
four opposite directions. And this can have disastrous consequences at national
level. Let us look at how this has played out in one poor country: Malawi.
Malawi has been trying, since 2007, to develop a comprehensive
national social suport policy. During that time:
1) The Productivists (aka the
World Bank) have been (a) pursuing their investments in public works through
the Malawi Social Action Fund (MASAF), and (b) experimenting with a pilot
Conditional Cash Transfer in Zomba;
2) UNICEF has been pushing its
Ten-Percent model, with a pilot first in Mchinji, and then expanding to a handful of other districts;
3) ILO and its Instrumentalist
partners have been assiduously fixing the joists for their Social Protection
Floor;
4) DFID has commissioned some
like-minded Universalists - HelpAge, EPRI and (it must be admitted) RHVP - to argue
the case for a universal social pension.
The result: stalemate. No wonder Malawi's Cabinet has still
not approved the policy, five years on!
In the meantime, the Government has shown very clearly where
its own "social support" policy priority lies: in its agricultural
input subsidy programme. So what should the donors have done? Instead of declaring that they didn't approve of
subsidies, instead of insisting that the national social support policy be
approved before they did anything, and instead of pursuing their opposing
policy agendas, they should rather have:
· jointly supported the Government;
· explored integrated ways to extend social transfers to the poor with no land or labour (as in the direct welfare support components of Ethiopia's PSNP and Rwanda's VUP);
· explored options for cash transfers to those who routinely sell their agricultural input vouchers, on the basis that there must be cheaper and more efficient ways to provide them with the cash they need;
· facilitated the inclusion of civil society and of beneficiaries in the national social protection debate;
· invested in necessary upfront expenditure, such as national identity systems;
· helped to build capacity at national and sub-national levels;
· promoted the institution of independent grievance and appeals procedures, and of social audits;
· explored innovative delivery systems;
· leveraged maximum private sector participation in the programme;
· funded a futures option on maize imports (as DFID and the World Bank had done successfully in 2005) to provide insurance against the next year when (not if) the harvest fails;
· invested in monitoring and evaluation to learn lessons and inform the evolution of the programme.
What a missed opportunity!
In conclusion, social protection still has a huge role to play in development; but it will only achieve its full potential if the Four Horsemen of the Donor Apocalypse reconcile their differences and unite to ride in the same direction as individual national Governments.
No comments:
Post a Comment