Here are some of its many drawbacks:
·
It is impossible
to do. First, of course, it is impossible to accurately identify the “poorest”,
especially in contexts where the majority of the population live on low incomes.
The charade that you can accurately measure and compare the poverty of different
households is manifestly absurd, as has been frequently documented.
We should all, at the very least, be open and honest that approaches to
targeting on the basis of poverty (whether community-based or proxy means
tested) are simply rationing mechanisms; and, in the case of the proxy means
test, are as arbitrary as a lottery.
·
It adds
cost and complexity. Even if a semblance of accuracy were possible at a
given point in time, it is prohibitively expensive and complicated to maintain
up-to-date information on comparative destitution, especially in countries
where incomes are highly dynamic. In all low- and middle-income countries, a
substantial proportion of the population moves in and out of poverty on a
seasonal or annual basis. It is fanciful to think that a metric collected one
year will have any validity in one year’s, three years’, or five years’ time.
·
It damages
social cohesion. Because the outcomes are so random and unintuitive,
poverty-targeting that chooses one household and excludes a nearly-identical
neighbour will inevitably create jealousies and social tensions.
·
It is
inequitable. In situations where many people are equally poor, to give an
arbitrary selection of them a comparatively significant benefit will catapult
the lucky few into a higher wealth category than the unlucky many. The
“have-nots” will become the “haves” and will remain better off than the new
“have-nots” until eventual re-targeting…when the iniquitous yo-yo will reverse.
·
It creates
perverse incentives. As soon as people understand that they will only
remain beneficiaries of a programme if they meet certain criteria of
deprivation, they will be faced with the perverse choice between remaining poor
and continuing to receive the benefit, or bettering themselves and losing it.
Why pour a concrete floor, put a tin roof on your house, or save for your old
age if, by doing so, you will be excluded from State benefits?
·
It rewards
dishonesty. Again, with a growing understanding of the system, some people
will be tempted to game it: they may borrow extra children from neighbours, feign
disability, hide assets, or deny ownership of small livestock. The result is
that dishonesty is rewarded and honesty penalised, which is damaging to the
moral fabric of society.
·
It incites
patronage. Giving anyone the discretion to influence the choice of
beneficiaries for a programme puts that person in a position of power. This
opens the door to abuse, patronage or exploitation. Even where such temptation
is resisted, there may nonetheless be a perception of patronage, which again
jeopardises the social compact.
· It stigmatises. Poverty-targeting demeans programme beneficiaries, the polar opposite of the desired effect of social protection, which is to include and dignify. Posting the names of beneficiaries on walls, for example, or announcing them in public, has the effect of stigmatising vulnerable people, not empowering them.
But these defects, while egregious, are not the real issue.
If you were an insensitive, extravagant, patronising bigot who didn’t care
about dignity, ethics or equity, you could probably live with them. The real
problem is the wider impact of such deficiencies on political support for
social protection. National politicians shy away from poverty-targeted interventions.
I challenge you to name one such programme that has led to an adequate – and
sustainable – fiscal commitment to social protection, or has increased the real
value of its transfers to beneficiaries over time.
Poverty-targeted programmes never become entitlements. As a
result, they never generate popular demand (except among a voiceless minority)
and, in consequence, they never gain political traction. Therefore, they never
generate adequate domestic fiscal space for improved social protection.
Let’s look at a few examples: first, the much-vaunted – but
poverty-targeted – Pantawid Pamilyang
Pilipino Program (4Ps) in the Philippines. Figure 1 shows the evolution of
the real value of the transfer since 2007: ever downwards. Worse still, as a
result of this 32 per cent reduction over ten years, recent
research by the World Bank has shown that some recipient children are now obliged
to work to cover the costs of attending school in order to avoid being
sanctioned or excluded from the programme.
Figure
1: Real value of the Philippines 4Ps transfer
Next, let’s look at a telling comparison between Malawi’s Social
Cash Transfer (SCT) and Lesotho’s Old Age Pension (OAP). Both programmes
started at around the same time and in response to the same problem: the
ravages of HIV/AIDS. But Malawi’s was poverty-targeted, based on the (baseless)
“10 per cent labour-constrained ultra-poor”, while Lesotho’s was
near-universal, targeting all citizens once they reached the age of 70 years. Malawi’s
has remained externally-driven, and is still – fifteen years on – more than 90
per cent funded by donors. Lesotho’s is (and has always been) fully
domestically-funded and is very much part of the political landscape, with
recent elections having been won and lost on competing pledges to increase the
value of the transfer. As Figure 2 shows, the very different trends in the real
value of the respective transfers is indicative of the difference between an
inclusive “social protection floor” and a poverty-targeted “social protection
flaw.”
Figure 2: Comparison between the real value of transfers in Lesotho’s OAP
and Malawi’s SCT
Finally, look at the evolution in Zambia’s Social Cash Transfer
scheme. Originally, like Malawi’s, this was tightly poverty-targeted at the “non-viable”
poorest 10 per cent. For its first ten years it was almost exclusively
donor-funded, and gained no attention from local politicians. It drifted
unconvincingly, expanding from one district to five, then to eleven; from 1,000
households to 8,000, then to 24,000. But at this point (see Figure 3) it
started experimenting with different categorical targeting approaches.
Suddenly, politicians sat up and took notice…and domestic funding started to
flow. In the five years since 2012, it has become essentially a near-universal
old-age and disability pension…and it has expanded exponentially: to nearly
600,000 households in all 108 districts of the country. Donor funding has
barely increased: the cost of the expansion has come from domestic resources.
Figure 3: Changes in coverage of
Zambia’s Social Cash Transfer scheme
What we are striving for, as social protection
practitioners, is programmes that are based on entitlement, that generate
increased domestic funding, and that maintain (or even raise) the value of
their benefits to the poor and vulnerable over time. We are not going to get
this from poverty-targeting. So please can we make a common resolution to
promote only inclusive approaches in 2018?
No comments:
Post a Comment