CoViD-19 has sparked a mass of interest in “basic income”.
South Africa’s Minister of Social Development has advocated it; Spain has
promised it on a permanent basis; UNDP has argued for it globally (at least on
a temporary basis); South Korea, Hong Kong and Singapore have used universal
cash transfers as a response to the pandemic, with Japan apparently also
planning to do so; Tuvalu is paying a monthly grant to every one of its
citizens for the duration of CoViD. The social protection world is abuzz that
basic income’s time has finally come, some 500 years after Thomas More wrote,
in his “Utopia”, that “it would be far more to the point to provide everyone
with some means of livelihood, so that nobody’s under the frightful necessity
of becoming, first a thief, and then a corpse.”
But the more you look at basic income, the less attractive
it seems, at least from a social protection perspective.
Let’s begin with what we mean by “basic income”. At least
that’s straightforward: you just give money to everyone. But actually it turns
out not to be so straightforward. The Basic Income Earth Network (BIEN),
probably the foremost global forum, proposes that “A Basic Income is a periodic
cash payment unconditionally delivered to all on an individual basis, without
means-test or work requirement”.
The first thing to note about this definition is that
“basic income” is synonymous with universal basic income: the
“universal” in “universal basic income” is tautologous, since “basic income” is
already paid to “all”. Wikipedia confirms this: “Basic income, also called
universal basic income (UBI), citizen's income, citizen's basic income,
basic income guarantee, basic living stipend, guaranteed annual income, or
universal demogrant…”. But it creates an inconsistency. If we think of an
alternate type of social security, say a “child benefit” or a “social pension”,
then a “universal child benefit” would be definitionally distinct from a “child
benefit”, and a “universal social pension” from a “social pension”, by virtue
of necessarily being paid to all members of that category rather than
just some. By contrast, in theory, there is an absolute requirement that basic
income must be paid to all individuals of all ages in a particular society.
BIEN expands its definition to separate out five key
characteristics of basic income:
·
Periodic: it is paid at regular intervals (for
example every month), not as a one-off grant.
·
Cash payment: it is paid in an appropriate
medium of exchange, allowing those who receive it to decide what they spend it
on. It is not, therefore, paid either in kind (such as food or services) or in
vouchers dedicated to a specific use.
·
Individual: it is paid on an individual basis –
and not, for instance, to households.
·
Universal: it is paid to all, without means
test.
·
Unconditional: it is paid without a requirement
to work or to demonstrate willingness-to-work.
The World Bank’s comprehensive “Exploring Universal Basic
Income: a Guide to Navigating Concepts, Evidence and Practices” (Gentilini et
al, 2020) begins by observing that: “The debate on a UBI is often chaotic
and without precise definitional contours”. It goes on to characterise basic
income along three different axes of social protection: that it is cash, rather
than in-kind; that it is universal, rather than targeted, and that it is
unconditional. These three criteria map well to three of BIEN’s five. The Bank
is not explicit in its classification that payments should be to individuals
rather than households, nor that they should be made at regular intervals. But
in its subsequent categorisation of different programmes, it does add an
additional consideration: that basic income should be state-led.
However, when you reflect more on these characteristics
through a social protection lens, it becomes clear that they are still incomplete:
·
Frequency – from a social protection perspective,
the frequency of payments matters. It is not enough to say (as BIEN does in its
definition) that payment must be “at regular intervals (for example
every month)”. Paying once every decade is “regular”…but useless for providing social
support. So, we need to be clear: the frequency of transfers should be monthly,
or at worst every two months.
·
Flat-rate – the concept of paying something to everyone
is clear, intuitive and appealing (at least to a universalist), but the
definitions above are coy about whether this should be at a flat rate to
everyone. But surely, logically it should? Otherwise, a basic income becomes
rather less simple and basic. Because if you then need to differentiate to give
different amounts to young children, older persons, those with disabilities,
those who are employed and so on, then you are not really solving the problems
of existing life-course social security. So, rationally, basic income should be
paid at a flat rate.
·
Coverage – The definition suggests that basic
income should be “paid to all”. But “all” of what? BIEN and the World Bank are
silent on this. But Wikipedia boldly ventures that it “can be implemented
nationally, regionally, or locally”, with nothing to define the scale of what might
be meant by “local”. But, surely, we need to be clear that we are not talking
about providing income support just to a single village (as a number of basic
income pilot programmes do): it has to be national in coverage, either to every
citizen or to every resident.
·
Duration – Especially from a social protection
perspective, income transfers have negligible value unless they are delivered
consistently over a sustained period, so that individuals can be confident of
making plans around them. So basic income, in common with all forms of social security,
must be multi-annual.
So, we find that we now have ten necessary characteristics
of basic income:
·
regular payments
·
at monthly intervals
·
in cash
·
universally
·
to individuals
·
at a flat rate
·
with full national coverage
·
unconditionally
· by the State
· on a pluri-annual basis.
Based on these characteristics, there has only been one operational
example of true basic income anywhere in the world: the Subsidy Reform
Programme in Iran, from 2010 onwards.
And this definition makes a mockery of many of the current
claims of providing basic income. Looking at programmes in the recent past, the
Basic Income Experiment in Ontario, Canada, was limited to a particular age
group (18-64), was household-based, was means tested, had a variable rate, and
didn’t provide cash (it was essentially a negative income tax); Finland’s KELA-run
programme targeted only unemployed adults, and only a small sample of those; and
Barcelona’s B-MINCOME is highly selective (even within its limited geographical
neighbourhood) among only those already having a file with social services, and
it is means-tested, household-based, age-restricted (25-60), variable-rate and
conditional (at least in some of its treatment arms)! Finally, the many
renowned basic income pilots (such as SEWA in India, GiveDirectly in Kenya, BIG
Coalition in Namibia) are by definition not national in coverage (or anywhere
near it – most cover less than 2000 individuals) and are not state-led.
Post-CoViD enthusiasm shows similar incongruity. South
Africa’s Minister rowed back fairly swiftly to clarify that she was only
talking about basic income for the 18 to 59 year age group (or perhaps as a
priority just “the most vulnerable groups of our population … the youth between
18 and 24 and the elderly between 50 and 59”). Spain’s “basic income” proposals
are household-based and tightly poverty-targeted. UNDP’s is explicitly
“temporary”. South Korea, Hong Kong, Singapore and Japan are only initiating
one-off (or two-off, in Singapore’s case) payments: furthermore, South Korea’s is
household-based, Hong Kong’s excludes under-18s, and Singapore’s is only for
over-21s. Even Tuvalu is proposing payments to its 11,500 citizens only for the
duration of CoViD-19. So, no imminent prospect of true basic income.
Perhaps basic income has a useful role in distributing
dividends generated by national resources and assets, such as the ongoing
Alaska Permanent Fund, the short-lived Human Development Fund in Mongolia, Macau’s
Wealth Partaking Scheme, the casino profits of the Eastern Band of Cherokee
Nations, or the one-off Scheme $6,000 in Hong Kong. But surely social
protection requires a more nuanced approach? This is because good social
protection (by which I mean inclusive rights-based life-course social
protection!) should reflect the vulnerabilities faced at each stage of the
life-course and should be designed in such a way as to help achieve the
government’s objectives for that stage. A flat-rate transfer to everyone is far
too blunt an instrument.
In most countries, for example, existing old age pensions are significantly higher than existing child benefits, reflecting their different objectives: a pension to allow people to live in dignity, to meet the increased costs of healthcare and to contribute to supporting others in the household; a child benefit to meet the objectives of good nutrition (for mother and child), early childhood development and access to education. Support to persons with disabilities often entails a higher transfer still, to compensate the additional costs involved in participating fully in society (which is not taken into account by a basic income). And transfers to people of working age should be designed primarily to support their engagement (or re-engagement) with the labour market, to recompense them for unemployment or unpaid work, for example in the care economy, or when they are sick. These different sets of objectives at different life-course stages require different programmes, often with different funding mechanisms, for example through a mix of contributory and tax-financed schemes.
What governments have an opportunity to do now, in response to CoViD-19, is not to introduce basic income across the board, but to fill the gaps that have been revealed in their existing programmes to move towards universal life-course coverage. Child benefits, old age pensions and disability allowances should be made universal, and integrated systems should be put in place to provide income support to all those of working age who need it (which in many countries has emerged as the most glaring lacuna). This could conceivably be in the form of a universal flat-rate transfer to all in that age group (though this would still not count as basic income by the strict definition). But it could also be achieved through judicious integration of contributory and tax-financed approaches to ensure that everybody receives such support when they need it.
That would indeed be a BIG step in the right direction, and
– for social protection purposes at least – a much better option than More’s utopian
vision!
No comments:
Post a Comment